Thursday, July 09, 2009

India's bad budget

Many economists/ media persons have tried to make the best out of Mr Pranab Mukherjee's budget. Unfortunately, their arguments are weak and unconvincing . Here is a government which had an opportunity to break free from the left. As we all know, the Left had consistently been stonewalling the reform initiatives for the past few years. Yet by sending out such confusing signals, the Congress has made it abundantly clear that the left was ( as Percy Mistry recently put it) " a convenient fig leaf for obscuring the inconvenient truth". The real opposition to reforms lies within the Congress. The party remains as socialist as ever. The way Mukherjee sang praises about Indira Gandhi's nationalisation of the banking system in the 1960s is a case in point.

Once we separate out the rhetoric from the substance, we see that the key messages from the finance minister/government are :

A) We will continue to waste the exchequer's money.

B) We know more than the markets.

C) We will continue to micromanage and meddle in the economy.

D) Accelerating the reforms process ( thereby encouraging entrepeneurship) is not a priority for us.

E) We can make any statements we like without substantiating data and get away with it.

F) Public memory is short and any commitments we make ( on fiscal discipline) can be conveniently overlooked at a later date.

Thursday, March 26, 2009

Prospects for the US Dollar

Before World War II, the developed countries were on the gold standard. For every dollar printed, there was a dollar's worth of gold in the vault. After World War II, under Bretton Woods, gold was notionally valued at $35 an ounce but the discipline of the gold standard was gone. America could now issue paper money as basically IOUs to the world, where each dollar could buy a dollar of gold. The gold didn't have to actually exist.

By 1971, thanks to the free spending of the Vietnam War and rising trade deficits, the credibility of the dollar came under threat.That year, Richard Nixon abolished the fixed price of gold. The US could now devalue the currency and expand money supply freely.

The US is now the world's biggest borrower. But this period of debt financed expansion and printing of money may have gone too far.That is why countries Like China, who are major investors in US T Bills have cautioned the US government to control the fiscal deficit. What a reversal. China actually advising US how to manage its economy!

Friday, March 06, 2009

Central and eastern European currencies

Ref Financial Times dt March 6, 2009
The Hungarian forint has hit a fresh record low against the euro following comments from Jean-Claude Trichet, president of the ECB. In response to a question about whether the ECB’s collateral framework could be expanded to include eastern European assets, Trichet said that ’”sticking to rules as they are is important”. Concerns over the region’s ability to cover its funding requirements in the face of tightening credit markets and a slowdown in global trade have driven down currencies in the region in recent weeks.

Earlier an FT editiorial mentioned that a probable solution is to pursue a flexible approach and allow early entry of some if not all these currencies into the Eurozone. Currently, the Mastricht Treaty rules remain rigorously enforced on countries outside the eurozone even as some insiders flaunt the rules. For example, euro candidates must keep inflation at most 1.5 per cent above the three lowest rates in the EU; those three rates will probably soon be negative. Many new EU members have pursued a disciplined fiscal policy. The Czech Republic and Poland almost meet the criteria. Estonia’s and Bulgaria’s high inflation can be blamed on the Maastricht criteria themselves. By maintaining stable exchange rates in a credit boom, these countries became wide open to capital inflows that inflated their economies.

Many countries in the region are now under pressure in markets that fear a balance of payment crisis. They can be helped by speeding up euro accession. A quicker entry into the euro for countries with proven fiscal responsibility will help stabilise exchange rates. The requirement of two years’ participation in the EU’s exchange rate mechanism before being admitted into the Euro should be waived.

In contrast to Trichet's pronouncement, the FT editiorial mentioned : "A currency union needs rules. They must in the future be applied more strictly than they have been across the eurozone. But today they must be interpreted flexibly. A prudent Poland should not be made to atone for the sins of profligate Italy."

Recession fears mount due to uncertainty

Ref Gillian Tett, Financial Times March 5 2009

In the past few weeks, concerns about a sharp decline in global economic activity have mounted. In part, this can be blamed on tightening of credit by banks. But the sheer speed and global nature of this slump suggest that psychology is also to blame. People are feeling gloomy and uncertain on almost every front.

In the financial markets, the collapse of Lehman Brothers has created huge worries about counterparty risk. Also financiers are finding it increasingly hard to engage in the market “hedging” strategies they used to employ to mitigate risk. The pattern of deleveraging and forced sales has been so intense that traditional price relationships have completely broken down. Trading models have gone haywire.

Western governments do not seem to be doing much to remove this sense of uncertainty. The Lehman collapse has sown a sense of terror about creditors losing money on any bank bonds they hold. Governments must persuade investors that banks are so healthy they cannot collapse. Alternatively they must promise to protect creditors if they do.

The US and many European countries are rolling out piecemeal solutions. Meanwhile, efforts to persuade the public that banks are healthy, have been unconvincing mainly because there is still so much uncertainty about asset values.

Thursday, March 05, 2009

Will the dollar remain strong?

Ref : Dollar strength will linger, Mansoor Mohi-uddin, Financial Times March 4 2009

What explains the strong dollar? The inability of non-US banks to roll over short term funding of investments in illiquid US assets has been a key factor behind the dollar’s strength since last summer according to Mansoor Mohi-uddin, managing director of foreign exchange strategy at UBS.

At the height of the credit bubble in mid-2007, major European banks’ dollar funding needs was around $1,300bn. As the credit crunch worsened after the bankruptcy of Lehman in September 2008, securing this funding became very difficult due to the severe disruptions in interbank and foreign exchange swap markets and in money market funds. Also, some central banks withdrew dollar foreign exchange reserves they had placed with commercial banks before the crisis.

To ease the dollar shortage, the Federal Reserve provided swap lines with other central banks in October 2008. These have been extended until October this year, reflecting the need of foreign banks to keep borrowing dollars from domestic central banks.

While the dollar funding shortage in global banking persists, the greenback may continue to be strong against the other major currencies.

Bank of England cuts interest rates to 0.5%

Ref : Norma Cohen Financial times, March 5 2009

The Bank of England’s monetary policy committee (MPC) cut its key interest rate by half a percentage point to 0.5 per cent on Thursday and rolled out a programme to buy up to £150bn in government gilts and corporate bonds. It is the first central bank in Europe to begin quantitative easing – in an effort to kick-start demand. The programme will begin with an initial £75bn of asset purchases, to be composed mostly of government gilts.

The size of the full programme will be up to a maximum of £150bn but £50bn of that may be used to support the purchase of private sector assets – corporate bonds and commercial paper.


The MPC agreed that in future meetings it would monitor the effectiveness of the programme in boosting money supply “and in due course, raising the rate of growth of nominal spending, adjusting the speed and scale of purchases as appropriate.”

In deciding on the 50-point rate cut, the MPC considered the forecast in its March inflation report, which implied a substantial risk of inflation undershooting its 2 per cent target in the medium term. Moreover, data released since that report had done nothing to suggest an improving economic outlook.

Paul Keating calls for a new global financial architecture

Former Australian prime minister writing in the Financial Times has stressed the need for democratisation of the global financial governance process and improved
policy coordination across the world. Keating suggests the need to radically restructure the IMF with a governance structure that truly represents the wider world it claims to serve.

Keating adds that big fiscal deficits and recapitalisation of banks offer only a temporary respite to the crisis. Fiscal policy also has its limits. The US federal deficit may hit $1,700bn this year, or about 13 per cent of gross domestic product. Clearly the US is reaching the limit. What we need is for deficit countries to save more and spend less and surplus countries to do the opposite. This savings imbalance will not be remedied unless the global governance structure changes.

For instance, China has no intention of dealing with its surpluses by letting its real exchange rate redirect national resources. We cannot fully blame China for this stance. Following the crisis of 1997, what every Asian government fears is the political consequence of capital outflow. A good example is Indonesia, where Suharto was forced out of office in 1998. Until international monetary governance is sufficiently democratised, or at least is made more representative, no major developing country, will fall in line.

For Keating, inclusion is the only way to make the world anew. If it happens, the impact on confidence will be profound. What the world badly needs today as the recession deepens is for confidence to be restored quickly.

ECB slashes interest rates to 1.5%

Ref Ralph Atkins, Financial Times March 5 2009

Eurozone interest rates have been slashed by a half percentage point to the lowest level ever. The interest rate in the Eurozone will fall from 2 per cent to 1.5 per cent, bringing the total rate cut since early October to 275 basis points.

But official borrowing costs are still higher in the Eurozone than in the US and the UK - highlighting the central bank’s conservative stance in relation to the US Fed and the Bank of England.

The latest cut came after ECB governing council members received updated forecasts that indicated much worse contraction than in previous projections, released in December.

Spain reported industrial production in January was 20.2 per cent lower than a year before. German engineering companies reported January’s foreign orders were almost 50 per cent lower than a year before.

Wednesday, March 04, 2009

AIG's huge losses.

Ref : AIG still facing huge credit losses
By Henny Sender in New York Financial Times, March 3 2009

AIG has declared a $62bn fourth-quarter loss and confirmed that it would give the US government a stake in its two biggest divisions as part of a fresh $30bn rescue.
Meanwhile more losses may follow. AIG retains $12bn in exposure to credit insurance on positions mostly involving subprime mortgages. As of February 18, AIG could have to pay counterparties up to $8bn on these positions.

Ben Bernanke, Federal Reserve chairman, expressed his strong sentiments in an appearance before the Senate budget committee: "If there is a single episode in this entire 18 months that has made me more angry, I can’t think of one other than AIG.There was no oversight of the financial products division. This was a hedge fund basically that was attached to a large and stable insurance company.”

AIG burnt its fingers badly when it moved agggressively into selling credit default swaps to provide credit protection for collateralised debt obligations.AIG ran into trouble when its credit rating was downgraded and the value of the CDOs it insured fell, This forced it to post tens of billions of dollars in additional collateral with its counterparties. Pushed to the wall, AIG had no option but appeal to the government for a bailout in September.

In November, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York set up a limited liability company called Maiden Lane III – backed by $5bn from AIG and borrowings of up to $30bn from the Fed – to deal with the crisis. Maiden Lane III would buy CDOs from AIG’s counterparties and then tear up the credit insurance issued by AIG.

In the days after the creation of Maiden Lane III, AIG and the Fed approached about 20 counterparties with an offer to buy CDOs. By the end of the year, Maiden Lane III had paid nearly $30bn for CDOs with a face value of $62bn. AIG paid $32.5bn to terminate the credit insurance on the CDOs, recognising a 2008 loss of $21bn. Counterparties received 100 cents on the dollar for the CDOs, but the prices paid by Maiden Lane III suggested that the CDOs were worth 47 cents on the dollar.

Tuesday, March 03, 2009

Land acquisition in India

Ref Leader, Business Standard March 3, 2009

Land acquisition remains one of the key factors which is slowing down industrial growth in the country.The government’s failure to get land acquisition and rehabilitation bills passed by Parliament before the elections is a setback to reforms in this area. The two bills — the Land Acquisition (amendment) Bill, 2007, and the Rehabilitation and Resettlement Bill, 2007, aimed at avoiding a repetition of the violent incidents that rocked Nandigram and Singur. The final version, passed by the Lok Sabha without debate and in the absence of the Opposition got stuck in the Rajya Sabha because of stiff resistance from opposition parties.

The Bill to replace the antiquated Land Acquisition Act of 1894 sought to balance the need for acquiring land for development with the interests of the land owners and moved the law quite significantly to the side of the land owners. Thus, it confined forcible land takeover to just three purposes — strategic use, public infrastructure projects and commercial ventures which are strictly in the public interest. Also industry would have to commercially buy 70 per cent of the land required for a project before the state government could step in to acquire the rest. Industry has complained in some cases that such a change in the law would have made it difficult to set up new units, because land acquisition would have become next to impossible. However, this is not really true. The experience with some of the special economic zones shows that land was privately acquired to a substantial degree, without the use of force.

The rehabilitation Bill, too, had some welcome stipulations—like undertaking rehabilitation prior to land takeover, and providing employment or equity participation to the affected families. The value of land goes up dramatically once it changes from agricultural to industrial. The benefit from this flows almost entirely to industry. It is only fair that those who did not get any benefit from such change of end use should get an additional benefit, in terms of jobs or shares.

However, the whole legislative exercise could have proved futile, since the amendments would not have been binding on states as they are free to have their own policies in these areas. Some state governments have already put in place their own land acquisition and rehabilitation policies. Considering this, it makes sense to leave it to the new government to decide on the best course of action.

Monday, March 02, 2009

Explaining the role of central banks in the sub prime crisis

Ref The Economist dt Sep 11, 2008

According to George Cooper of JP Morgan, one of the main reasons for the global financial melt down is that central banks have subscribed to one economic philosophy in an expanding economy and quite another when the economy is contracting. When things are going well, central banks leave the markets alone. But at the merest hint of crisis, central bankers cut interest rates to stimulate their economies and prevent asset prices from falling. Indeed, this is what the Fed under Greenspan did. Greenspan argued that it was impossible to spot bubbles while they were inflating. Instead, he felt that central banks should quickly respond once the bubble had burst.

This school of thought believes that prices reflect all available information. On that basis, asset prices are always “right”, there can be no bubbles and central banks should not intervene to restrain speculative excess. Even if there is a temporary mispricing, the market will correct itself.

Cooper argues that markets are far from efficient. Investors may simply be unable to get enough information to make correct judgments about the value of securities, or indeed may be given misleading information by insiders such as company executives or salesmen from the financial-services industry.

During a market crash, central-bank intervention to prop up markets is often popular. There are few people who relish banking collapses or recessions. But it creates problems in the long run. The first is that consumers (and companies) are encouraged to borrow, not save, thanks to the low level of interest rates and a belief that central banks and governments will always rescue them if things go wrong.

The second danger is that the system becomes progressively less stable as risk-taking is encouraged. Instead, central banks should permit some short-term cyclicality in order to purge the system of excesses. They can do this by preventing excessive credit creation. This means that credit growth should not be far ahead of economic growth.

Letting the markets have their way would risk a repeat of the Great Depression. But the danger of bailouts is that central banks may inflate another credit bubble, saving the economy from disaster in the short term but raising the stakes still further when the next crisis comes around. The Bear Stearns, Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac and AIG rescues, suggests the world is heading in that direction.

Sunday, March 01, 2009

India's growth story at a cross roads

Till the recent slowdown, we had taken India's growth for granted. But now circumspection has increased. It is a good time to look at some of the structural issues which are impeding growth. The Economist dt Dec 13, 2008 ran a detailed feature on India. Here I look at few key points covered in the report.

In 2005 some 456m Indians, or 42% of the population, lived below the poverty line. In 1981, the numbers were 420m and 60% respectively. Clearly poverty in India is not falling fast enough. India has 60m chronically malnourished children, 40% of the world’s total. In 2006 some 2.1m children died in India, more than five times the number in China.

Some 65% of Indians live on agriculture, which accounts for less than 18% of GDP. Shifting them to more productive livelihoods would be hard.

India continues to be plagued by fiscal indiscipline. Public expenditure has risen by over 20% in each of the past two years. But the spending has not been productive. Instead, the government’s largesse was handed out in the usual wasteful ways—on oil and fertiliser subsidies and public-sector pay increases—and on some high-profile welfare schemes where a lot of leakages can be expected.

If India is to sustain a growth rate of 8% or higher, it will need to manage four potential constraints- infrastructure, education, labour laws and land laws.

The infrastructure is bad. It takes an average of 21 days to clear import cargo in India; in Singapore it takes three.

India’s 3.3m km road network is the world’s second-biggest, but most of it is in bad condition. National highways account for only 2% of the total, and only 12% of them, or 8,000km, are dual carriageways. By the end of 2007 China had some 53,600km of highways with four lanes or more. India’s urban roads are choked.

India faces an acccute shortage of power. Last year peak demand exceeded supply by almost 15%. According to the World Bank, 9% of potential industrial output in India is lost to power cuts. Some 600m Indians are not connected to the electricity grid at all.In the next five years, the government plans to increase India’s generating capacity by an annual 14%, or 90,000MW. China added 100,000MW in 2007. But India last year added only about 7,000MW.

Roughly 14m Indians are now being added to the labour market each year. They cannot all work for IT companies. Indeed, because of underinvestment in education, many lack the necessary livelihood skills.

Our labour laws continue to be drag. Our labour markets lack flexibility putting insiders at a tremendous advantage vis a vis job seekers.

Land aquisition continues to be nightmare. Recall Singur. Unless this issue is resolved, there will be strong incentives for industrialists.

Clearly there are many challenges ahead for the next govt. In the past 5 years, high growth came about to favourable circumstances and the dynamism of the private sector, not because of a visionary govt. But in future, things may not be that easy. If our leadership cannot rise to the occasion, we can expect China to increase the already large gap further.

Will UK, Iceland, Denmark and Sweden join the Euro?

Ref : The Economist dt December 13, 2008

The assets controlled by Britain’s banking system amount to 450% of GDP. This has drawn inevitable comparisons with Iceland. Like that Nordic country, Britain does not have a global reserve currency, to draw on if it needs to act as lender of last resort. Britain has access to currency swap lines from the world’s biggest central banks, which would help it prevent a run on the banks. But the cost of this insurance will make London less competitive as a global financial centre. Among larger European countries the British government’s exposure to its banking sector is by far the highest. Switzerland, Denmark and Sweden are also not too different from Iceland. Will all these countries now seriously think in terms of embracing the Euro? Going by the current levels of public and political sentiments, only Denmark seems a possibility.

Saturday, February 28, 2009

India’s GDP growth slows sharply to 5.3%

Ref : Financial Times February 27 2009

Indian economic growth slowed to just 5.3 per cent in the last three months of 2008, its lowest growth rate in the last six years. India’s economy seems to have been hit by the global crisis far harder than our ruling politicians have thus far admitted.

The turn of events suggests that a sustained period of 9%+ growth will not be easy for India. Just because China did it for decades does not mean that we are already there.

Even though we are different from China in that we are not so heavily dependent on global trade, the parts of the economy which have generated rapid growth in the past decade, namely the IT and BPO sector are global. At the same time, in the last three months of 2008, other sectors too have not done well. Manufacturing declined 0.2 per cent, owing to insuficient domestic and global demand. Agricultural output also shrank by 2.2 per cent.


The sharp slowdown will increase pressure on the RBI to cut interest rates. Although the RBI has lowered its benchmark rate by 350 basis points in the last few months, falling inflation means real interest rates are realtively high.


But for higher government spending, growth would have been even slower. But this is not a sustainable solution. We know that government spending in our country is highly inefficient. Moreover, the government has little room for further stimulus given its already large fiscal deficit, estimated at 11.4 per cent of GDP. And even this could be an understated figure as our politicians and bureaucrats are adept at playing with numbers.

The pitfalls of low volatility

Ref The Economist, Jan 15, 2009

Volatility refers to the standard deviation of the returns of a portfolio. Volatility contributes to risk. Prudence demands that volatility is monitored and controlled.
But low-volatility should also ring alarm bells. Is the volatility low because the fund manager is buying illiquid assets. Because such assets are traded rarely, prices do not move much.

Or has the manager adopted a strategy with highly skewed returns; lots of small gains but the occasional catastrophic loss. Nicholas Nassem Taleb, the proponent of the Black Swan is famous for this argument. For example, the manager could be selling insurance against a big stockmarket fall. Most of the time such falls do not happen. But when the market falls, the insurer may have to pay out all his previous gains. Such strategies have been described as “picking up nickels in front of steamrollers”. Recall what happened to the monoline insurers last year.

Low volatility may also be the result of fraud. Many firms try to beat profits estimates by a small amount every quarter. Indeed one of the motivations of creative accounting is to reduce the volatility of earnings.

What we need is a change in attitude among investors. Life is volatile. Economies do not grow at a steady rate for ever. Markets do not rise at a steady pace and business conditions do not allow for a smooth rise in profits. So we must acccept volatility as a given in business. A portfolio manager who is committing high returns with low volatility may well be running a Ponzi scheme.

Debt is no longer chic

Ref The Economist, Feb 19, 2009

In 1980, more than 60 American non-financial companies qualified for the AAA rating from Standard & Poor’s (S&P). Now there are just six. In 1987 just 38.1% of issuers in the American bond market were rated as speculative, or “junk”. In 2007 junk-bond issuers made up most of the market for the first time.

Traditionally, debt has scored over equity in the sense that it reduces the cost of capital, creates tax benefits and most importantly imposes discipline. When managers know they have to pay back the capital they have raised, they will be careful. With equity, this pressure to pay back does not exist.

But as the Economist article explains, managers’ self-interest seems to have taken over at some point. Managers started using cash to buy back equity to boost earnings per share. They also favoured debt over equity to make the share price more volatile, and thereby make the option more valuable. Debt was also often used to finance acquisitions as part of empire building, a rtrend encouraged by investment banks, which had an incentive to recommend debt issuance and acquisitions, to earn fees. While all this was happening, activist shareholders such as hedge funds put pressure on companies to pay out surplus cash.

It is only in the current recession that the dangers of debt are becoming more apparent. The default rate is now rising rapidly. S&P believes that nearly 14% of bond issuers will fail to meet their obligations this year. It is difficult to roll over new debt, given the credit crunch. Meanwhile, suppliers are insisting on instant payment from companies with weak balance-sheets.

The problem for companies is there may not be much they can do right now to rectify the situation. A depressed market is hardly the time to issue equity. Also if an equity issue is announced, the share price tends to fall. For many American companies, the share price is in single digits. And any further fall may have catastrpohic consequences. After all the share price itself is a proxy for default risk as per the well known Merton Model.

Friday, February 27, 2009

The Citi bailout

On February 27th, Citigroup and the Treasury reached a deal that took a big step towards partial nationalisation. Through conversions of preferred stock, the government will own 36% of Citi, though the final figure will depend on how many preferred shares private holders agree to swap.
As the Economist mentioned today, the latest bail-out will give the government real control of Citi. The government does not need to own a majority of the shares in a bank to wield whatever influence it likes. With somewhere near 36% of Citi, control of decision-making will be complete—if it is not already. Citi already has to clear strategic decisions with regulators.
Citi approached regulators about the conversion, worried that further losses would as the recession and housing crisis deepen. Citi will need more capital in the coming months. And its current market cap of about $ 14 billion looks really puny indeed.

The crisis in Iceland

Ref The Economist dt Dec 13, 2008

The collapse of the krona and nationalisation of the country’s three largest banks in early October, 2008 have left Iceland facing a huge financial crisis.This is probably the biggest banking failure in history relative to the size of an economy. How did this happen?
Iceland ilustrates the dangers of a large globalised banking system in a small domestic economy. In 2007 Iceland’s three main banks made loans equivalent to about nine times the size of the booming economy, up from about 200% of GDP after privatisation in 2003. Only about one-fifth of those loans were in kronur; interest rates on these were very high. SO many Icelanders instead borrowed from their banks in cheaper currencies such as yen and Swiss francs.
But after the banks collapsed in early October, the currency slumped and domestic interest rates rose sharply. Exchange controls imposed in the heat of the crisis have severely restricted access to hard currency.
The IMF forecasts that the economy will contract by 9.6% next year. Many workers have been laid off. Many young Icelanders, who have never known unemployment, are expected to lose their jobs.
With unemployment rising, citizens talk openly about defaulting on their home and car loans. Principal payments on local-currency mortgages are indexed to inflation, which is expected to be 20% this year. This and their foreign-currency exposure means many households’ debts have roughly doubled in krona terms.
The failure of the banks may cost taxpayers more than 80% of GDP. Relative to the economy’s size, that would be about 20 times the Swedish government's banking rescue act in the early 1990s. The cost would also be several times that of Japan’s serious banking crisis a decade ago.
The crisis was fulelled by the aggressive business model of Iceland’s two largest banks, Landsbanki and Kaupthing Bank. These banks could attract only paltry sums in the domestic market. In 2006, they decided to use the internet to attract foreign deposits, using the cost savings from online banking to offer higher interest rates to savers. These banks were soon sucking deposits away from bricks-and-mortar banks across Europe. When Landsbanki collapsed in October, the country ended up owing $8.2 billion to foreign internet depositors of its banks, or about half of Iceland’s entire GDP.
Now the debate has intensified whether Iceland should join the Euro. Here opinion is divided among Icelanders. And even if the country decides to join the Euro zone, it will take quite sometime.

Tensions in the Eurozone

Spreads on the ten-year government debt of Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain over that of Germany have widened sharply. Rating agencies are closely watching the fiscal positions of the five countries.

The recession in the early 1990s saw various currency crises within Europe’s exchange-rate mechanism (ERM) , particularly in 1992, when Britain had to leave the ERM. One motive for creating the euro was precisely to avert such crises. Members of the Eurozone have at least been spared pressure from the foreign-exchange market.

But there is a price to pay for stable exchange rates. That is taking the shape of lost competitiveness, big current-account and budget deficits, and increasing concerns about creditworthiness.

In the 1990s the weaker economies in the euro zone made strenuous efforts, through fiscal tightening, wage restraint and product- and labour-market reforms, to satisfy various criteria and qualify for euro membership. But once they passed the test they relaxed, lulled into a sense of complacence that membership of the single currency would be enough to solve their economic problems. At the same time they enjoyed the benefits of a boom due to the euro’s lower interest rates. Once in the euro, and deprived of the chance to devalue again, they should have pursued structural reforms at home to make their economies more competitive. They should have emphasised fiscal discipline to offset the euro’s easier monetary policy. But they did not.

Now as these countires are entering a period of deep recession, the hidden costs are being exposed. In Spain and Ireland property bubbles that were inflated in part by the switch to low euro interest rates have burst spectacularly. In Greece, Italy and Portugal a steady loss of wage and price competitiveness is eroding growth. and in all these countries, public finances seem to be in a mess.
The bond markets are especially concerned about Greece and Ireland; but fears are growing even over such big countries as Italy (where public debt stands at over 100% of GDP) and Spain.

Argentina on the Danube

This is the title of an article which recently appeared in The Economist.
Many East European countries seem likely to default on their debt. At least the markets think so. The financial system in this region has combined badly run local banks with loosely overseen subsidiaries of Western ones. During the boom years, this system absorbed credit from abroad, leading to big current-account deficits. Because of reckless lending, often in foreign currencies, bad debts are likely to increase. Some local banks have failed; many of the foreign-owned ones now depend on their parents’ willingness to keep financing them. Unfortunately for them, those parents have plenty of problems at home.

All the countries are not facing the same problem. Poland and the Czech Republic have cut interest rates to cope with the slowdown but this has sent their currencies tumbling. This has increased the burden on households that have mortgages in Swiss francs or euros. Some countries like Hungary ( 100% of GDP) have a big external government debt. For Latvia, Estonia, Lithuania and Bulgaria, the strong euro is a problem. They have pegged their currencies to it.

All in all, this seems to be the most turbulent period for Eastern Europe since the collapse of the Soviet Union.

Swiss private banking at a cross roads

The core of Swiss banking, namely client confidentiality and privacy is being challenged. In the rich world, the mood against all big banks has turned nasty. The US has already taken a belligerent stand. At the G20 meeting in April, European leaders may discuss potential sanctions against tax havens that refuse to hand over information held by their banks.

As the Economist recently mentioned , at risk is up to $2 trillion in offshore assets held in Swiss private banks. There are also important questions at stake about the reach of the state and a citizen’s right to privacy.

Those who press for an end to banking secrecy argue that people who hide their assets want to evade taxes probably as much as $255 billion a year around the world. However, private banking is not just about tax planning. Clients have other fears too - divorce settlements, expropriation by fickle governments and thieving criminals. Also much of the new money that flowed into Switzerland in recent years may have come from countries with low or no personal income taxes, such as the Gulf. Moeover, a rapidly increasing share of money coming from European countries with high rates of tax is declared to the authorities.

Whatever be the case, the Swiss private banking industry is fighting a grim battle for survival.